This is a weekly thread in which we read through books on and related to imperialism and geopolitics. Last week's thread is here.
Welcome to the second week of Michael Hudson's Super Imperialism: The Origin and Fundamentals of US World Dominance! I'm reading the Third Edition, but I imagine most of the information is the same if you have an earlier edition.
We are reading one chapter per week, meaning we will finish in June. Obviously, you are totally free to read faster than this pace and look at my/our commentary once we've caught up to you.
Every week, I will write a summary of the chapter(s) read, for those who have already read the book and don't wish to reread, can't follow along for various reasons, or for those joining later who want to dive right in to the next book without needing to pick this one up too. I will post all my chapter summaries in this final thread, for access in one convenient location. Please comment or message me directly if you wish to be pinged for this group.
This week, we will be reading Chapter 1: The Origins of Inter-Governmental Debt, 1917-1921, which is approximately 20 pages.
This week is Chapter 1 of Superimperialism, which is only 18 pages.
@RedDawn@hexbear.net @Cowbee@hexbear.net @kittin@hexbear.net @Sebrof@hexbear.net @TrippyFocus@lemmy.ml @OrionsMask@hexbear.net @0__0@hexbear.net @SummerIsTooWarm@hexbear.net @mbt2402@hexbear.net @BanjoBolshevik@hexbear.net @BodyBySisyphus@hexbear.net @NinjaGinga@hexbear.net @Test_Tickles@hexbear.net @luddybuddy@hexbear.net @Coca_Cola_but_Commie@hexbear.net @niph@hexbear.net @redline@lemmygrad.ml @glimmer_twin@hexbear.net @MF_COOM@hexbear.net @MiraculousMM@hexbear.net @StarkWolf@hexbear.net @StillNoLeftLeft@hexbear.net @BGDelirium@hexbear.net @THEPH0NECOMPANY@hexbear.net @devils_dust@hexbear.net @iridaniotter@hexbear.net @Ehrmantrout@hexbear.net @quarrk@hexbear.net @RaisedFistJoker@hexbear.net @Lemmygradwontallowme@hexbear.net @darkmode@hexbear.net @PaulSmackage@hexbear.net @FunkyStuff@hexbear.net @IceWallowCum@hexbear.net @Babs@hexbear.net @PerryGirl@hexbear.net @Rojo27@hexbear.net @OgdenTO@hexbear.net @GoodGuyWithACat@hexbear.net @2Password2Remember@hexbear.net @Sasuke@hexbear.net @thethirdgracchi@hexbear.net
I was not gonna ask, because I'm busy reading a lot else, but I finished chapter 1 in no time so might as well pay attention and get pinged. So Add me please
add me to the list fam
coincidentally I just started reading this book at the exact same time you guys did
I'm beginning to suspect the first edition (which is the one I'm reading from) is measurably different than the Third, as my first chapter is actually 36 pages long and entitled "Birth of the Post-Lenin Imperialism" but whatever, I'll post quotes and keep following along as best I can. Anyway, this chapter seemed to chronicle the failed American efforts to subordinate and dominate Europe post-WWI. Of course this failure led directly to WWII. Regardless, it's a perfect example of the Kissinger sentiment that "it may be dangerous to be America's enemy, but to be America's friend is fatal." Some quotes:
The overwhelmingly governmental nature of US international finance capital, which had begun during the war, was further emphasized when the war ended. What was being experienced was the earliest manifestation of what was to evolve in other countries, though in far cruder form, into National Socialism. Germany under Hitler, Italy under Mussolini, and Spain under Franco, each subordinated the individual interests of its separate capitalist groupings to a national political purpose without injuring these interests, but subjecting them to more-or-less effective regulation depending on the character of the regime. Precisely this, but in far more benign fashion, was implicit in the assumption of the role of the nation's and the world's main credit functions by the government of the Untied States. (pg 6)
So Hudson here draws a direct parallel between fascism and US policy around international credit, one which is still clearly on display today with Trump et. al subordinating the international interests of the tech giants and American manufacturing to his policies around tariffs.
The Allies did, indeed, need German funds to pay their armaments debts to the United States; failure of the United States to adjust their debts to the receipt of German reparations bled the Allies as the Allies bled Germany. US Government finance capital would not even make the accommodation to its debtors which commercial creditors are often prepared to make. As soon as the war ended the American government asked its allies to begin paying, with interest, for the arms and related support financed by US Government credits. In the history of warfare no ally had requested such payments for its military support. The provision of arms to allies, by universal custom, had been written off as a war cost. This time the credits were officially kept on the books. The eagle had unsheathed its claws. (pg 13)
Funny how the exact same dynamic is playing out in Ukraine, with Trump asking for "repayment" in the form of mineral rights for US arms. The US has been trying to dismantle and subordinate Europe for a century at this point, using finance as its primary weapon, and it's worked tremendously well for them. Of course this first attempt leads directly into the escalating tension that explodes into WWII. As Hudson writes, "It was a period in which the most extortionate of nationalistic acts were inspired by frustration at an untenable economic situation imposed upon the world by the United States." (pg 15)
United States policy was thus to treat Germany, the recent enemy, as a country in need of protection against the effects of a fall in prices, but to treat England, the recent ally, as a nation to be trodden down if a fall in world prices should occur. The recent enemy was to become a war of the US Government; the recent ally to be punished. Because this ally was the world's great imperial power, and Germany its recent challenger for imperial supremacy, the interpretation is justified that the United States had its eyes set lustfully on the British Empire. To swallow the Empire, the United States must first dislodge it. England must be forbidden the fruits of victory; Germany established again as England's rival. This self-same policy was to recur after World War II. (pg 23)
Obviously very different circumstances, but again we see this dynamic play out with the US reproachment of Ukraine and Russian peace talks. Russia must be uplifted, the EU/Ukraine punished. I don't think this time it's going to work, because Russia already has a "no limits" partnership with China, but I'm sure that's the hope of the US right now. Again emphasizes how ruthless American imperialism can be.
In essence, every American administration, from 1917 through the Roosevelt era, employed the strategy of compelling repayment of the war debts, specifically be England, to so splinter Europe that, politically, the whole of Europe was laid open as a possible province of the United States... [they would have achieved it] had the world not tumbled into universal depression from which the United States was not only not exempt but became, in the event, the principal sufferer from the collapse of its own creating. The first great foray of US governmental finance capital into world power politics had ended in ignominious failure, and ultimately in a war of dimensions vaster than even World War I, a war which the United States had no desire to bring about but no deep feeling that it must prevent. (pg 34)
Of course the US would learn its lesson and course correct post-WWII, with its far more successful gambit.
I'm beginning to suspect the first edition (which is the one I'm reading from) is measurably different than the Third, as my first chapter is actually 36 pages long...
I just picked up my copy from the library, but on page viii of the Third Edition he talks about some of the differences:
I spent 1973 expanding the original first chapter into what are now four chapters in order to better explain the ascendancy of U.S. inter-governmental capital.
. . .
In 2002, as the aggressive character of America's drive to control the world economy along self-serving lines was becoming especially blatant, Pluto Press published a revised and augmented edition of the book. That edition unfortunately was riddled with typographical errors and misspellings. I sent a long list of corrections, but nothing was fixed, so I bought back the rights in 2019 and prepared for the book to be reset, taking the opportunity to edit the manuscript for greater clarity.
Ah that's actually really helpful. I guess I'll read the PDF for the next few chapters and then go back to my physical copy after.
Oscardejarjayes linked the third edition here if you don't mind reading a pdf
Overall I found this chapter a lot easier to follow and a lot more interesting than the introduction. Hopefully that bodes well for the rest of the book, since usually my eyes glaze over as soon as I start reading about finance.
A few choice quotes I highlighted while reading:
One of the first acts of Congress following declaration of war by the United States therefore was to vote government funds to finance arms loans to the US
This kind of implies that the reason we joined the war at all was to prevent our debtors from defaulting, rather than any kind of altruistic motive. The duplicitous yankee will literally join a war three years late for the sole purpose of impoverishing his allies and then refer to himself as "back to back world war champ"
US Government represntatives likewise had originally told their allies not to worry about conditions of repayment, which were to be settled after victory had been won, implicitly on nominal terms (emphasis mine)
Already in 1918 the duplicitous yankee was pioneering the use of strategic ambiguity!
The foundation of Europe's offical indebtedness was nothing more than the narrow, legalistic and ultimately bureaucratic assumption that debt, because it was debt, was somehow sacrosanct
"... There is abundant use in France, in Belgium, and in Russia for men and materials, and a large part of the industrial equipment to be used there might well be manufactured in [the US]." Some of these reconstruction resources were transferred to Germany and Austria, with official US sanciont, in order to help stave off revolution there (emphasis mine)
The duplicitous yankee was running an open beta of Operation Gladio even in nominally enemy countries. The more I learn about history the more clearly the inherent evil of this country comes into focus
Germany was burdened with a sum calculated to reimburse the Allies for most of the damage wrought during the war, a sum that exceeded the total value of Germany's corporate assets. It simply lacked the resources to provide the Allies with the funds necessary to amortize their debts to the United States
As someone else mentioned in this thread, Kissinger was really cooking when he said "it may be dangerous to be America's enemy, but to be America's friend is fatal"
In these respects intervention by the US Government limited the potential spheres of expansion of private US finance capital in both Europe and its colonial areas
I found this very surprising because the idea of the US government working against the interests of capital is simply unthinkable today. This type of short-term pain for long-term gain thinking is totally alien to today's bourgeoisie, and therefore to their puppets in Washington.
[Quoting Schulze-Gaevernitz] "I understand by Super Imperialism that stage of the capitalist epoch in which finance capital mediates political power internationally, to acquire monopolistic control - and monopoly profits - from natural resources, raw materials and the power of labor, with the tendency towards autarky by controlling all regions, the entire world's raw materials"
Its been a couple years since I read Lenin's Imperialism (I didn't participate in the previous reading group), so I might be talking out my ass here, but this definition of imperialism doesn't feel that different from what I recall from Lenin. Can somebody explain to me what the difference is?
I think Hudson would actually disagree with that Schulze-Gaevernitz quote. For Hudson (as far as I understand him thus far), finance capital is distinctly not mediating political power internally to do something. In fact the opposite is happening; the state is disciplining finance capital and using financial tools as a method to securing global hegemony. It's not Wall Street that's securing the USD as the global reserve currency and forcing countries to buy US Treasuries, it's the United States government and its vast military apparatus (as the stick). The US has subordinated private finance capital to public finance capital. Super imperialism doesn't need to acquire monopolistic control of any resources, raw materials, or labour; its control comes from being in charge of the financial system which facilitates these things. The US does not control anything about China's factory system. However, because it can print USD, and maintains a system where USD is recycled back to itself at no "cost," it can purchase all of those goods created by China's factories for "free." The imperialism Schulze-Gaevernitz is describing is almost exactly like the imperialism of Lenin and Hobson, yes. But it is meaningfully different from Hudson's super imperialism, where the method of control is not over resources or labour, it's over the monetary system itself which can be used to purchase those things.
Thank you, this is a very helpful explanation. I was a bit confused because Hudson is using the term super-imperialism and Schulze-Gaevernitz was using Uberimperialismus, which is basically just super-imperialism in german.
but you cleared it up for me. Lenin's conception of imperialism was rooted in production and has to do with control of resources intended to be used for producing goods, where as Hudson's super-imperialism is rooted in finance and therefore has to do with control of systems of moving money around. this tracks for me and is pretty easy to understand in an age where nearly everything has been financialized
It's akin to how Amazon has become such a massive megacorporation despite actually making things not being its focus; if you can control how the goods get from one place to another (such as from other corporations to consumers), then that automatically provides you with a massive degree of control over both the corporations and consumers if you can obtain a monopoly position and prevent anybody from taking your place. It's a fairly elegant solution to the problems of traditional imperialism, though it does ultimately still produce its own contradictions that result in it falling apart (as we increasingly see in the present day).
My question to the book, was that policy against private capital interests something which was seen as above private capital, or something which was ultimately, in the final analysis, in its interests? What kind of push back was received? And is this subsumption of interests how he would define the monetary policy of fascism? Those parts of the chapter kinda flowed as one and I didn't follow the logic entirely.
Is there a PDF somewhere on the internet that I can use?
https://annas-archive.org/md5/3e18cc4a0165d3f703e388f4f810c1a3
https://www.youtube.com/playlist?list=PL8R-uen6FfFzJl-ja3MZiE3qMcWnA5a7i
Found an audiobook on youtube from user Chet Ozmun for those interested in listening at work or the gym or while cooking or while doing dishes or while folding laundry or while feeding a baby whatever other situation you may find yourself in where holding a book is not possible or ideal.
Here's my notes/summary of Chapter 1!
expand
Before World War 1, claims on foreign assets were held predominantly by private investors in the form of equity interests or mortgage bonds on income-producing assets in corporations, like railroads or banks. While large government debts existed, these were usually held by private investors, not by foreign governments. Additionally, international investment into productive assets like factories (or into governments) was designed to generate profit (or tax revenue) that would then be given to investors, but also to the corporations/governments being invested in. This meant that they would be able to repay those debts to the investors.
World War 1 changed this setup. Debts between governments were now predominant and massive. And the United States was the creditor nation for most of this debt. Most of this debt was in the form of the Inter-Ally debts which, in the early 1920s, stood at $28 billion, and Germany’s reparations debt, which stood at $60 billion - with interest. Unlike the private investment of before the war, these claims were not in productive resources or increasing the tax revenue of the allies, therefore meaning they could not easily generate the money to pay off the debt.
During the war, the Allies shifted through various means $7.5 billion into the US to pay for weapons, which was their financial limit by the time the US entered the war. When the US entered the war, one of the first things it did was to allow the US government to create funds to finance weapon shipments to the Allies, and, not wanting the US population to take on the burden of repaying this debt, they specifically made these loans to Europe, and not just free sharing of resources and money.
It is notable that this differs from how wars were previously financed, with Britain using subsidies to finance its allies over the centuries, and the French using subsidies to fund the American War of Independence. These were granted monthly and thus could be stopped at any time if their performance was lacking. Using loans had been done before, but the economic problems in the debtor countries post-war created antagonisms. The American War of Independence cost France $700 million and France asked for no compensation beyond $6 million in loans, and even this was eventually retired. Between the Napoleonic Wars and World War 1, most wars were local and between two countries and thus did not require inter-ally debts.
As World War 1 begun, there was no real conception that a loan system would be pursued and the Europeans assumed that the subsidy system would be used as normal. Even the United States initially seemed genuine about not intending for the debts to be repaid; with them intending on giving billions to France as a gift for their help during the War of Independence. Additionally, the Europeans holding off the Axis while the Americans trained their troops (as opposed to having to send inexperienced men to the front) was also seen as part of paying off any debt. However, when the US entered the war, they said that it had no interest in territory nor any colonial ambitions, and legally argued that this meant they could not use the subsidy system and instead had to issue loans - and these loans would eventually harden into inter-governmental claims that had to be repaid in full.
The overriding assumption here, of course, was that debts simply had to be repaid - they were sacred. But this massive amount of debt was a shock to a fragile system that had survived because it is represented by real assets and the amounts lent were not too large; Keynes predicted that the WW1 debts would never be repaid, and this would lead to a breakdown in world investment and trade, and probably more war.
In the aftermath of WW1, Congress denied loans to Europe for reconstruction. Because Europe could not afford to pay for US agricultural prices, this therefore threatened a US agricultural and industrial collapse. The Wilson Administration decided to bypass Congress and acted as if this war was still happening through some creative legal justifications. Additionally, it was suggested by one report that the US use its men and materials to help Europe during reconstruction; resources were indeed given to Germany and Austria to prevent socialist revolution there.
The US did not officially end its war with Germany until the Treaty of Berlin in the summer of 1921. It then began the process of ensuring the collection of debt from the Allies. They initially made overtures to American ambassadors to adjust the debt, but were rebuffed, and the US threatened that they would not provide credits to a government that planned to support a policy that would delay the payment of debt. The Allies remained lax about the issue until early 1922, when the US established the Foreign War Debt Commission, which established that the debt should be repaid within 25 years, and at an interest rate no lower than 4.5%.
The US explicitly and repeated stated that they would not allow the debts to the Allies to be cancelled, despite insistence from Britain and France. Despite the US advising the Allies to be moderate with Germany, the US was not at all moderate with the Allies. The immense cost of the war to Europe was not seen by the US as a good reason for Europe to punish Germany yet further with added debts, and yet the US regarded its own argument - that it was not an ally but an associate in the war - as completely ironclad as to why it should not cancel the loans to the Allies.
Ironically, the US private sector suffered as a result of this policy. To repay its debt, Germany would be forced to undersell American and Allied producers; meanwhile, the debt payments ruined the postwar financial and commercial price stability that was needed for international trade. The entire policy was rather short-sighted - it stipulated that Germany repay the Allies but did not provide any major method to do so, such as by exporting its products to the Allies; nor was Germany receiving much foreign investment. In fact, the US increased tariffs on Germany and the Allies from 1921 to 1933 to protect its own industries; this was to counteract the Allies depreciating their own currencies to make their products cheaper so they could earn the money to pay their debts. Meanwhile, the Federal System acted to insulate the US from the inflation resulting from gold inflows. Despite now possessing much of the world’s gold, and the sterling on the way out, the US and its dollar was not yet ready to take its place.
Germany was bled white by the Allies demanding reparations far above what it could have paid, and Germany was only kept functioning by lending from the US. The US also began to intrude on the foreign loan processes of US private investors, preventing loans to nations that had not made arrangements to fund and pay their debts to the US. It also demanded that any loans paid would go to productive investments, so as to generate the money for the loan to be repaid. Of course, the fact that the Inter-Ally debt to the US was non-productive was neither here nor there.
While the German debt to the Allies could, through legal processes, have been appealed, reduced, or even cancelled, the Allied debt to the US could not have been altered, meaning the Allies were, in a sense, under a more harsh imposition from its ally than Germany was to its enemies. Indeed, Germany’s annual payments were scaled down from 7 billion gold marks in 1920 to 2 billion marks in 1929, but the Allies received no similar kindness. With increasing American tariffs, the only way for the Allies to obtain the funds to repay the US was through German reparations, and Germany simply did not have the money and resources to pay this. This was not merely the standard degree of capitalist or national greed; Britain and France both cancelled Belgium’s debt towards them; the US did not, despite the debt being smaller.
In all, the US became the world creditor because of the actions of its government. It was not because of private investment abroad or through foreign expansion. Usually, governments followed private interests abroad, to colonize foreign lands and provide military support to the capitalists to take the land from the natives and ensure other nations could not then steal this land from them. It was more rare that the government took the initiative and forced the private sector to follow them. No longer was this true - the government was responsible for the majority of US investments overseas, and it did not get involved in underdeveloped foreign lands, but instead with a Europe that had a greater industrial output than themselves. If the US had not committed to the war with its military, American capitalists could have dominated the exhausted continent and generated the money to do so with military deals to the various battling powers, and taken Europe’s colonies for themselves. From this coldhearted capitalist perspective, involvement in WW1 was a mistake for the US.
The US becoming the singular creditor for much of the world was an unforeseen development in imperialism. Lenin, Kautsky, Hobson, and Hilferding expected the growth and concentration of finance capital in the international sphere, and thenceforth to peace (Kautsky) or to war (Lenin). While Lenin was right in the short term about it leading to war, they - and most everybody else - did not adequately predict was the US becoming the world creditor, and even more importantly, what the consequences of this would be. The government subordinated the (at least short-term) interests of its national bourgeoisie to that of the government. This was the earliest manifestation of what would become more developed by the coming fascist governments in Germany, Italy, and Spain - the capitalists subordinated to a national political purpose (although not to the capitalists’ detriment necessarily).
Idk about you Americoids, but I was always taught the rise of Nazi Germany was largely a result of the unpayable debts to Allies. I was never taught that it was the US who demanded unreasonable loan repayments from the Allies which drove them to demand German reparations.
This chapter was pretty eye opening and suffice to say, I'll emphasize that aspect when I teach it in the future.